We are frequently told that information technology has
been and will be leading us to a grand and glorious future where innovative
applications will provide us with wondrous new things. Yet at the same time, many of us who have
been around for a long time have observed some rather disconcerting trends. Jobs that used to last for decades now last
years—provided one is lucky enough to have an actual job and not a contingent
assignment. A college education was once
a passport to a position with job security and the expectation of rising
wages. Now a college education is often
a passport to a position that was once performed by high school graduates, and
the financial reward is derived not from rising wages but from the fact that
high school graduates’ prospects are falling faster than those of college degree
holders. There is a narrowing
educational door through which fewer and fewer highly skilled people are
admitted. Wealth is being accumulated
ever more quickly, but concentrated in fewer people. We seem to be moving in a direction where
wealth determines political power. How
does society benefit in any way from these developments?
Are these the concerns of one who is too resistant to
change? Or is there in fact something
deceptive and harmful in what technology is doing to society?
Martin Wolf provided some interesting insights into what
has been transpiring in an article in Foreign
Affairs: Same as It Ever Was. He signals where he is headed by providing
this subtitle:
“Why the Techno-optimists Are
Wrong”
According to classical economic reasoning, increases in
wages will naturally follow from increases in productivity of workers as the
bounty from this increase is shared between labor and capital. Therefore, if one wishes to claim a new “industrial
revolution” based on information technology, one should be able to indicate
gains in productivity as evidence. Wolf
points out that during the supposed “revolution” the rate of gain in
productivity has actually been falling.
“In reality, the pace of economic and social transformation has slowed in
recent decades, not accelerated. This is most clearly shown in the rate of
growth of output per worker. The economist Robert Gordon, doyen of the
skeptics, has noted that the average growth of U.S. output per worker was 2.3
percent a year between 1891 and 1972. Thereafter, it only matched that rate
briefly, between 1996 and 2004. It was just 1.4 percent a year between 1972 and
1996 and 1.3 percent between 2004 and 2012.”
“On the basis of these data, the age of rapid productivity growth in the
world’s frontier economy is firmly in the past, with only a brief upward blip
when the Internet, e-mail, and e-commerce made their initial impact.”
Perhaps one
way to differentiate between the second industrial revolution of the past
century and the presumed current one is that the past provided access to things
that were desperately needed, while the current one must first create a desire
for the products it provides.
“Just consider the shift from a
world without telephones to one with them, or from a world of oil lamps to one with
electric light. Next to that, who cares about Facebook or the iPad? Indeed, who
really cares about the Internet when one considers clean water and flushing
toilets?”
If one wishes to consider what a real technological revolution
is, consider this statement that Wolf provides from the economist Robert Gordon:
“Electric light and a workable
internal combustion engine were invented in a three-month period in late 1879.
The number of municipal waterworks providing fresh running water to urban homes
multiplied tenfold between 1870 and 1900. The telephone, phonograph, and motion
pictures were all invented in the 1880s.”
Those who promote a “third industrial revolution” claim
that economic statistics do not capture the added value provided by recent
innovations. A smartphone, for example,
is worth much more than its sale value.
Wolf will have none of this.
“These points are correct. But
they are nothing new: all of this has repeatedly been true since the nineteenth
century. Indeed, past innovations generated vastly greater unmeasured value
than the relatively trivial innovations of today.”
A true revolution must generate enormous social and
economic benefits to the world.
“The motor vehicle eliminated
vast quantities of manure from urban streets. The refrigerator prevented food
from becoming contaminated. Clean running water and vaccines delivered drastic
declines in child mortality rates. The introduction of running water, gas and
electric cookers, vacuums, and washing machines helped liberate women from
domestic labor. The telephone removed obstacles to speedy contact with the
police, fire brigades, and ambulance services. The discovery of electric light
eliminated forced idleness. Central heating and air conditioning ended
discomfort. The introduction of the railroad, the steam ship, the motor car,
and the airplane annihilated distance.”
Wolf grants that computers, the internet, and related
goods are very important, but he fails to find anything that generated beneficial
changes comparable to those produced in the last century. In fact, one can make the argument that the
information age has been at least partially responsible for the range of ills
discussed at the beginning of this article.
“Yet perhaps paradoxically,
recent technological progress might still have had some important effects on
the economy, and particularly the distribution of income, even if its impact on
the size of the economy and overall standards of living has been relatively
modest. The information age coincided with—and must, to some extent, have
caused—adverse economic trends: the stagnation of median real incomes, rising
inequality of labor income and of the distribution of income between labor and
capital, and growing long-term unemployment.”
The information age has also contributed to the ease with
which jobs and factories could be eliminated from local economies and shipped
elsewhere. The net result for a country
like the United States is that products have become cheaper, but wages have
been driven lower while the basics of education, housing, and healthcare have
become much more expensive.
The basic premise of the information age is that machines
and computer-driven logic can perform many tasks better than humans. Therefore, working humans will be replaced as
they become obsolete. Where this process
ends, no one knows. There are still those economists who will
claim that new technologies always create more jobs than they destroy. This belief seems to be based on the
observation that the last industrial revolution drove people from farms and
into our large urban areas—and provided them with jobs and prosperity
(eventually). But that has already
happened. It can’t happen again, so
where are these new jobs going to come from?
The hallmark of the information age is that successful
companies can be produced quickly with little need for physical capital and
even less need for employees. A handful
of people can create something that generates enormous revenues (think
Facebook). Great wealth can be created
without the need to share it with anything so old fashioned as employees. Where is the modern counterpart to the auto
industry that generated a world-wide network of suppliers of parts and services
and employed millions?
Wolf provides an interesting discussion of where we might
be heading. His main point is that
technology does not have a life of its own.
It does not have the right to wander wherever it wishes and create or
destroy whatever it chooses. Not all
activity is progress, and not all efficiencies and innovations are beneficial.
“….new technologies bring good
and bad. We must believe we can shape the good and manage the bad.”
Innovation emerging from the current digital era has
enormous potential to allow people to live better lives.
“….we will have to reconsider
leisure. For a long time, the wealthiest lived a life of leisure at the expense
of the toiling masses. The rise of intelligent machines would make it possible
for many more people to live such lives without exploiting others. Today’s
triumphant puritanism finds such idleness abhorrent. Well then, let people
enjoy themselves busily. What else is the true goal of the vast increases in
prosperity we have created?
However, a more expected result is less encouraging.
“It is also possible that the
ultimate result might be a tiny minority of huge winners and a vast number of
losers. But such an outcome would be a choice, not a destiny. Techno-feudalism
is unnecessary. Above all, technology itself does not dictate the outcomes.
Economic and political institutions do. If the ones we have do not give the
results we want, we will need to change them.”
We have a choice before us. We can use our ability to create wealth to
produce a society where leisure takes up an ever greater fraction of our
time. We would of course have to
re-educate ourselves in order to be able to use that time to provide ourselves
some satisfaction.
Or, we could conclude that it would be better to create a
society where there was a true full-employment program. As we watch our shabby infrastructure become
ever shabbier, it is not difficult to envisage tasks that need to be done. Jobs could be created in the arts, sciences,
and various service areas that would be beneficial to society.
Both options will produce better results than would occur
if we do nothing. What is necessary is a
vast redistribution in wealth. Society
can make that happen. It would be
democracy in action. Wolf provides us
with a reminder of what the rights of society include.
“Property rights are a social
creation. The idea that a small minority should overwhelmingly benefit from new
technologies should be reconsidered. It would be possible, for example, for the
state to obtain an automatic share of the income from the….property it protects.”
Martin Wolf is Chief Economics Commentator for the Financial Times.
No comments:
Post a Comment