In his book, The Memory Chalet, Tony Judt
reminisced over the history of Marxism and discussed its ability to “capture”
the minds of many intellectuals who would become so enthralled with its view of
historical progression that they would use the promised end to justify terrible
means to attain that end. He referred to
Marxism as a secular religion. Similar
to deity-based religions, secular religions can provide a feeling of belonging
to something bigger than oneself; it makes available a framework in which all
things can be explained; decisions which otherwise might be difficult to make
are predetermined. The dark side of
religious belief, secular or otherwise, is that it can produce goals so desirable
that adherents resort to unworthy methods to reach those goals. In one case the legions march off with God on
their side, in the other, History is on their side.
Judt makes the provocative comparison between Marxism and
free-market capitalism and concludes that Marxism has been superseded by another
secular religion—one of which we are barely aware.
“Our contemporary faith in “the
market” rigorously tracks its radical nineteenth-century doppelgänger—the
unquestioning belief in necessity, progress and History. Just as the hapless British Labour chancellor
in 1929-1931, Philip Snowden, threw up his hands in the face of the Depression
and declared that there was no point opposing the ineluctable laws of
capitalism, so Europe’s leaders today scuttle into budgetary austerity to
appease ‘the markets’.”
“But ‘the market’ like
‘dialectical materialism’—is just an abstraction: at once ultra rational (its
argument trumps all) and the acme of unreason (it is not open to
question). It has its true
believers—mediocre thinkers by contrast with the founding fathers, but
influential withal; its fellow travelers—who might privately doubt the claims
of the dogma but see no alternative to preaching it; and its victims, many of
whom in the US especially….proudly proclaim the virtues of a doctrine whose
benefits they will never see.”
“Above all, the thrall in which
an ideology holds a people is best measured by their collective inability to
imagine alternatives. We know perfectly
well that untrammeled faith in unregulated markets kills: the rigid application
of what was until recently the ‘Washington consensus’ in vulnerable developing
countries—with its emphasis on tight fiscal policy, privatization, low tariffs,
and deregulation—has destroyed millions of livelihoods. Meanwhile, the stringent ‘commercial terms’
on which vital pharmaceuticals are made available has drastically reduced life
expectancy in many places. But in
Margaret Thatcher’s deathless phrase, ‘there is no alternative’.”
Marxism was based not on data or past history, but on a
theory of how society must evolve. Similarly,
free-market capitalism also is not based on data or past history, but on a
theory of how economies (and societies) must evolve.
The policies associated with the term free-market
capitalism used above can also be referred to as neoliberal economic
policies. One must be careful to not
confuse liberal economic policies with liberal political policies. Liberal economics refers to free-market ideas
and is inevitably promulgated by politically conservative people. Liberal economic concepts were first
formulated in response to the industrial revolution. They included “invisible hands” and other
intellectual constructs promoting the wisdom of unfettered markets. Liberal policies were thought to have been
dominant in the long period that terminated with the onset of two world wars
and the Great Depression. The period after
World War II led to an era of intense government intervention as societies
tried to recover from that tumultuous period.
This was a period of exceptionally high economic growth. By
around 1980, politically conservative economists campaigned to reinstate the
policies presumed to have been in place in the prewar liberal years, thus they
are referred to as neoliberals. The
neoliberals, in that process of becoming ascendant, managed to bring the period
of high growth to an end.
Ha-Joon Chang, an economist at Cambridge University,
provides a comparison between the claims of free-market capitalists and the
actual history of economic development in his book Bad Samaritans: The Myth of FreeTrade and the Secret History of Capitalism. Chang provides us with a concise version of
the neoliberals’ view of economic history.
“According to this history,
globalization has progressed over the last three centuries in the following
way: Britain adopted free-market and free-trade policies in the 18th century,
well ahead of other countries. By the
middle of the 19th century, the superiority of these policies became so
obvious, thanks to Britain’s spectacular economic success, that other countries
started liberalizing their trade and deregulating their domestic
economies. This liberal world order,
perfected around 1870 under British hegemony, was based on laissez-faire industrial policies at home; low barriers to
international flow of goods, capital and labour; and macroeconomic stability,
both nationally and internationally, guaranteed by the principles of sound
money (low inflation) and balanced budgets.
A period of unprecedented prosperity followed.”
Chang is gentle enough to refer to this mangling of
reality as merely “misleading.”
“This history of globalization
is widely accepted. It is supposed to be
the route map for policy makers in steering their countries towards
prosperity. Unfortunately, it paints a
fundamentally misleading picture, distorting our understanding of where we have
come from, where we are now and where we may be heading for.”
Chang identifies a particularly egregious example of how
Britain practiced “free trade” in the period when it was supposedly setting the
example for a period of “unprecedented prosperity.”
“This was a particularly
shameful episode, even by the standards of 19th-century imperialism. The growing British taste for tea had created
a huge trade deficit with China. In a
desperate attempt to plug the gap, Britain began exporting opium produced in
India to China. The mere detail that
selling opium was illegal in China could not possibly be allowed to obstruct
the noble cause of balancing the books.”
When China confiscated a shipment of opium, the British
declared war, defeated China, and forced it to accept a humiliating treaty (the
Treaty of Nanking) that ceded Hong Kong to the British and denied it the right
to set its own tariffs. In this way free
trade was introduced to China.
“The truth is that the free
movement of goods, people, and money that developed under British hegemony
between 1870 and 1930—the first episode of globalization—was made possible, in
large part, by military might, rather than by market forces. Apart from Britain itself, the practitioners
of free trade during this period were mostly weaker countries that had been
forced into, rather than had voluntarily adopted, it as a result of colonial
rule or ‘unequal treaties’ (like the Nanking Treaty), which among other things,
deprived them of the right to set tariffs and imposed externally determined
low, flat-rate tariffs (3-5%) on them.”
The goal of British foreign policy was to create a system
whereby Britain could obtain raw materials at low price from its colonies or
other poor countries, convert those goods into manufactured commodities, and
resell them to the same countries at a premium.
Not surprisingly Britain, and other countries that could attain similar
power, entered a period of “unprecedented prosperity.” The rest of the world didn’t do nearly as
well.
Forcing a developing country into a free trade
environment prematurely, as neoliberalism demands, is harmful to the long term
prosperity of that country. Developing
countries, by definition, are in a position to sell only low-technology goods
or raw materials. Developed countries
have advanced technologies and skills that allow them to produce more highly-valued
goods. If a country like South Korea
followed neoliberal advice they would still be selling fish in hopes of earning
enough to buy autos and electronics from the United States or Europe. Chang points out that the trick to becoming a
wealthy country is for a poor country to sell what it can on the open market
and forego consumption of goods available on that market. The easiest way to do this is to impose high
tariffs on imports of manufactured goods.
This provides the dual purpose of limiting the flow of funds out of the
country and it collects a tax that can be used to subsidize the development of
more competitive technologies. This is
the path Britain and the United States followed. They became interested in “free” trade only
when they thought they were powerful enough to control some parts of the market.
“This simple but powerful
principle—sacrificing the present to improve the future—is why the Americans
refused to practice free trade in the 19th century. It is why Finland did not want foreign
investment until recently. It is why the
Korean government set up steel mills in the late 1960s, despite the objections
of the World Bank. It is why the Swiss
did not issue patents and the Americans did not protect foreigners’ copyrights
until the late 19th century.”
“It took Toyota more than 30
years of protection and subsidies to become competitive in the international
car market, even at the lower end of it.
It was a good 60 years before it became one of the world’s top car
makers. It took nearly 100 years from
the days of Henry VII for Britain to catch up with the Low Countries in woolen
manufacturing. It took the US 130 years
to develop its economy enough to feel confident about doing away with tariffs
[tariffs in the US remained at 40-50% until World War I and were the highest of
any country in the world]. Without such
long time horizons, Japan might still be exporting mainly silk, Britain wool
and the US cotton.”
The neoliberal path to prosperity derived from this false
history includes the following:
“….a country needs to privatize
state-owned enterprises, maintain low inflation, reduce the size of government
bureaucracy, balance the budget (if not running a surplus), liberalize trade,
deregulate foreign investment, deregulate capital markets, make the currency
convertible, reduce corruption and privatize pensions.”
The problem is that while no wealthy country, including
Britain and the United States, utilized these policies in becoming wealthy,
undeveloped and developing countries are being advised—and often forced—to
follow them.
“In relation to the developing
countries, the neoliberal agenda has been pushed by an alliance of rich country
governments led by the US and mediated by the ‘Unholy Trinity’ of international
economic organizations that they largely control—the International Monetary
Fund (IMF), the World Bank and the World Trade Organisation (WTO). The rich governments use their aid budgets
and access to their home markets as carrots to induce the developing countries
to adopt neo-liberal policies. The IMF
and World Bank play their part by attaching to their loans the condition that
the recipient countries adopt neoliberal policies. The WTO contributes by making trading rules
that favour free trade in areas where the rich countries are stronger but not
where they are weak (e.g., agriculture or textiles).”
Neoliberal economic policies were developed in wealthy countries. Not surprisingly, they work to maintain
existing wealth at the expense of robust economic development in potential
competitors.
“Free trade demands that poor
countries compete immediately with more advanced foreign producers, leading to
the demise of firms before they can acquire new capabilities. A liberal foreign investment policy, which
allows superior foreign firms into a developing country, will, in the long run,
restrict the range of capabilities accumulated in local firms, whether
independent or owned by foreign companies.
Free capital markets, with their pro-cyclical herd behavior, make
long-term projects vulnerable. A high
interest rate policy raises the ‘price of future’, so to speak, making
long-term investment unviable. No wonder
neo-liberalism makes economic development difficult—it makes the acquisition of
new productive capabilities difficult.”
Returning to the theme of neoliberlism as a secular
religion, any religion—secular or otherwise—is created in order to provide an
orderly framework to a disorderly world.
The creators must also derive comfort from this framework, in the sense
that it justifies actions that they feel necessary to their wellbeing. The rich-world economists who derived liberal
policies and their neoliberal acolytes who continue the rote promotion of them have
replaced an unpleasant history of forceful domination and unabashed rent
gathering with one that attributes all that occurred—and all that will occur—to
economic forces as inevitable as the laws of physics. In other words, belief has replaced scholarly
research.
And we will all suffer the consequences. Chang provides numerous examples where
acceptance of neoliberal policies by countries has limited their economic growth. The data collected by Thomas Piketty,
discussed here, is consistent with
the notion that the liberal policies presumably in place prior to World War I
produced a long era of low growth and ever growing inequality of wealth. The 30 years or so after the two world wars,
which might be described as a Keynesian or social democratic era, was a time of
exceptional growth and decreasing inequality.
The returning dominance of neoliberal policies has again led to a period
of decreasing economic growth and increasing economic inequality. Of course there are always other things going
on that might ruin a good story, but if the neoliberals can create comforting tales, then so can I.
No comments:
Post a Comment