In a complex and rapidly changing economy it is easy to
conclude that there is an uncontrollable dynamic at work: the world moves
according to the flow of technology and no one knows where that will lead. If the trend is to create a few economic winners
and a lot of losers, then that is just the way it has to be. Anthony B. Atkinson refuses to accept the
inevitability of such market solutions.
In his book, Inequality: What Can Be Done?, he continually reminds us that
government, as the representative of all the people, can and must play a role
in determining where technology might lead us.
Atkinson is concerned with identifying actions that are
consistent with economic growth and will assist in limiting the continuing
increase in inequality. He arrives at 15
distinct proposals for actions that could be taken, and suggests several others
that require more study. The very first
addresses the influence of the government as an investor in technological
progress. He points out that the
research that has provided us with the high-tech gadgets we have so come to
love was directed and funded by the federal government. The government has a definite role to play in
developing technology, and it also has a role in defining how technology will
be implemented.
“….when making decisions
supporting innovation—whether concerned with financing, licensing, regulating,
purchasing, or educating—the government should explicitly consider the
distributional implications.”
A number of companies have sprouted in recent years that,
under the mantle of economic efficiency, have attempted to replace full-time
regulated workers with part-time workers available on demand who receive little
in terms of benefits. Take Uber, for
example. What are the “distributional
implications” of this trend? If the
result is that a new category of low-paid day-laborers is being created to
compete with full-time workers with benefits, then the government could and probably
should intervene.
The last decade has seen many semi-skilled jobs replaced
by innovative uses of technology. The
result has been movement of workers into less-skilled, lower-wage positions in
service industries. It is often assumed
that service jobs are less amenable to innovation and increases in
productivity. Atkinson believes this is
a false assumption, and when it comes to a critical service
provider—government—it is a dangerous assumption. The efficient administration of governmental
services is of the utmost importance in a healthy society.
“The achievement of an equitable
society depends to a considerable degree on the effectiveness of the public
administration and the quality of its dealings with citizens. Repressive administration may be cheaper, but
a fair society needs to ensure that its operations—in the fields of taxation,
public spending, regulation, and legislation—are just, transparent, and
accepted. This requires resources. Moreover, as societies become richer, so too
they become more demanding in their standards.”
Those who are experiencing social or economic difficulty
are most in need of a public administration designed to facilitate the
dispersion of aid.
“Economic inequality is often
aligned with differences in access to, use of, or knowledge of information and
communication technologies. For
middle-class taxpayers, filing a tax return on-line may be a time-saving
operation, but for a person who has just become unemployed, applying for benefits
on-line may be a worrisome challenge.”
A few examples from the United States will illustrate
Atkinson’s point about the need for efficient public administration if fairness
and justice are to be maintained. Since Atkinson
brought up the issue of tax returns, let’s begin there.
For most people, filing a tax return is a matter of
gathering together information that is already known to the Internal Revenue
Service (IRS), specifying that information in a form and sending it on to the
IRS so it can check to see if the data has been properly reported. It is immediately apparent that there is an
unnecessary step here. Why not have the
IRS accumulate the information and convert it into a tax assessment specifying
either a bill for any underpayment of taxes or a declaration of an overpayment
and eligibility for a refund? That is
exactly what the IRS must do anyway to check a submitted tax form. The person could then choose to accept the
assessment or enter modifications for items that had been missed or were
incorrect and resubmit it. This process
is in place in a number of countries and seems to work just fine.
The investigative website Propublica explains why such a
reform cannot happen in our country in the article by Liz Day: How the Maker of TurboTax Fought Free, Simple Tax Filing.
“Imagine filing your income taxes in five minutes — and for free. You'd
open up a pre-filled return, see what the government thinks you owe, make any
needed changes and be done. The miserable annual IRS shuffle, gone.”
“It's already a reality in Denmark, Sweden and Spain. The
government-prepared return would estimate your taxes using information your
employer and bank already send it. Advocates say tens of millions of taxpayers
could use such a system each year, saving them a collective $2 billion and 225
million hours in prep costs and time, according to one estimate.”
“So why hasn't it become a reality?”
“Well, for one thing, it doesn't help that it's been opposed for years by
the company behind the most popular consumer tax software — Intuit, maker of
TurboTax. Conservative tax activist Grover Norquist and an influential computer
industry group also have fought return-free filing.”
In an ideal
world, the government would be striving to make the tax collecting process as
simple and transparent as possible, by providing pre-filled returns for as many
people as possible. That is what
productivity in the service sector is all about. In fact, the IRS could provide the exact same
service that Turbo Tax provides—and provide it for free! How is that for productivity?
Instead, we
have commercial companies who exert their influence by throwing money around to
protect their parasitic revenue streams.
They are assisted by ideologues like Grover Norquist whose goal is not
efficient government, but rather the failure of government. He and his cronies in the Republican Party
wish to starve the IRS of funds and watch it perform so poorly that people will
resist paying any federal taxes.
For many, this
conflict between government efficiency and corporate or political profit is of
little concern. Unfortunately, it is
often those with the least earnings who are forced to get assistance from
for-profit agencies in order to file their tax forms. Financial records become complicated when one
makes a lot of money. They also become
complicated when one earns little income and receives public assistance. If some people have their way, the process
will grow even more complicated.
The Bloomberg Editorial Board published a
note titled How to Make the Tax code Even Worse. Here we are warned that one
of the most effective tax features—one that has long had bipartisan support—is
being undermined by corporate greed and political opportunism.
“Consider a scheme Congress may
soon take up for some individuals applying for the earned income tax
credit, once a relatively straightforward process. If a report from the Senate
Appropriations Committee is heeded, what was once a one-page form for claiming
the credit could expand to four or five pages, padded out by pointless and
bewildering new questions.”
“The likely result would
be that those eligible would either forgo their credits or hire tax
services for help. As it happens, H&R Block, the largest such service,
helped write a report recommending the changes. Complexity has its advocates.”
In addition to the corporate profit motive, there are the
politicians who believe that any assistance to a low income person is a
disincentive to work. Any welfare
assistance should therefore be small in amount, difficult to obtain, and be of
short duration. That provides an
explanation why some would be in favor of more complex tax reporting for the
earned income tax credit—it is better to harm 10 people than to let one person
get more than is allowed under the law.
Nowhere is government more inefficient and more purposely
harmful than in its administration of the welfare system. Kaaryn Gustafson, a law professor at the
University of Connecticut, published an article in the Journal of Criminal Law
and Criminology in 2009 titled The Criminalization of Poverty.
“Lost in these contemporary
understandings of welfare is the association of welfare with wellbeing,
particularly collective, economic wellbeing. Many of the current welfare
policies and practices are far removed from promoting the actual welfare of
low-income parents and their children. The public desire to deter and punish
welfare cheating has overwhelmed the will to provide economic security to
vulnerable members of society. While welfare use has always borne the stigma of
poverty, it now also bears the stigma of criminality.”
“Throughout the 1970s, '80s, and
'90s, the value of the welfare grant, adjusted for inflation, declined
dramatically. The weighted average maximum benefit per three-person family was
$854 in 1969 (in 2001 dollars), but plummeted to $456 by 2001. It became
increasingly hard for welfare recipients to cover their most basic
expenses-food, clothing, and rent-with their welfare grants. Unable to survive
on welfare checks and facing barriers to employment, many welfare recipients
turned to other sources of income, whether help from kin or participation in
underground labor markets, and attempted to hide those sources from the welfare
office for fear of losing the small checks they received.”
The government was purposely made less-efficient with the
express intent of limiting access to assistance to those unable to keep up with
complex reporting requirements. Social
workers who were once directed to provide assistance to those in need became
fraud detectors whose goal was to find cheating and withdraw assistance.
“Office caseworkers, hired to
replace the social workers, processed the routine paperwork that welfare
recipients regularly submitted to the office to document their continuing
financial need. In a process known as "churning," the federal
government increased the amount of information and paperwork required to
determine welfare eligibility, and denied benefits to low-income families who failed
to keep up with the paperwork. Income-eligible families were removed
from the aid rolls for their failures to provide verification documents in a
timely manner.”
Being caught and punished for some violation of the rules
(the most common of which seems to be missing a mandatory meeting at the
welfare office) is referred to as sanctioning.
States have the discretion of punishing an individual by limiting his or
her access to funds or they can choose to punish an entire family for one
member’s sins with a full-family sanction.
“….a study conducted by Yeheskel
Hasenfeld found that approximately half of the sanctioned adults surveyed did
not know they had been sanctioned. For these
families, the welfare system may seem so complex, arbitrary, and mystifying
that they cannot determine why their benefits are fluctuating. This suggests
that rather than creating a set of incentives that will ‘make work pay,’ the
current welfare system is simply punishing people who cannot figure out how the
system works.”
More on our current welfare system can be found in Race and the Criminalization of Welfare.
Atkinson is certainly correct in assuming that government
provision of services can be made more efficient. He is also correct in concluding that those
most in need of government assistance have much to gain. Inefficient government does contribute to
inequality.
No comments:
Post a Comment