There is much to learn from Thomas Piketty’s book Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Perhaps
the most fundamental lesson is that much of the last century was a unique
period in social and economic history.
The experiences and conclusions garnered from living in and studying
this recent era may not be appropriate for a future in which the world returns
to more normal circumstances.
Two world wars and the intervening Great Depression
created enormous social and economic damage.
The period of rebuilding after World War II generated a large amount of
economic activity. This was also the
period in which a number of underdeveloped countries, particularly in Asia
began to acquire modern economies. For
them, this was a period of rapid economic growth as well. It is easy to conclude, after living through
this period, that rapid growth is the norm for a healthy economy. Piketty warns us that that may be a dangerous
assumption.
The table below is from his book and is made available by
Piketty here.
Roughly half of growth in world GDP can be attributed to
population growth. What is desired is
GDP growth as an indicator of whether or not the income of the average citizen
is growing or not. To acquire that
knowledge the population growth must be factored out. Piketty nearly always uses per capita GDP to
capture that effect. Below is a more
detailed historical tally of per capita growth by continent.
Note that the only periods of sustained high per capita growth
(3% or more) are found in Europe and Asia in the immediate postwar years, and
in Asia with the emergence of China and India as rapidly growing economies. Note also that the average rate of economic
growth in the developed countries of Europe and America since the beginning of
the industrial revolution has been a modest 1%.
Piketty breaks out the growth rate history of Western
Europe and North America in the figure below.
Note that Western Europe with its supposed burden of
inefficient “welfare state” policies actually performs a bit better in recent
years than the more economically unrestrained states of North America.
Piketty believes the developed world is returning to a
long-term condition of low growth—on the order of 1.0-1.5%. The data in the above figure supports that
claim. This is equivalent to the growth
rate that persisted in the century before World War I, a period of great
concentration of wealth and extreme inequality.
Piketty warns us that we may be reverting to similar conditions as we
look to the future.
One of Piketty’s principle observations is the
relationship between economic growth (g) and return on investment of capital
(r). He treats wealth and capital as
interchangeable quantities, defining wealth as anything that possesses a market
value. If r is much greater than g then
the possessors of wealth will continue to reap returns much greater than those
who only possess their wages and wealth will grow inexorably. Consider the following figure.
Throughout history the annual return on capital has been
in the range of 4-5.5%. Note that this
figure does not include any deduction for taxes on wealth or on income from
wealth. For most of history such taxes
were essentially nonexistent. It wasn’t
until the shocks of war and depression began early in the twentieth century
that the extreme need for state income initiated income and estate taxes
broadly across the developed world. The
results of that development are obvious in the chart below.
After taxes and capital losses are included in the return
on capital, the rate of return actually falls below the rate of growth g for a
time. This means that during the postwar
period the importance of labor-derived income became much greater and in the
developed countries led to a broader distribution of wealth. More people earned enough to purchase homes
for example. Home ownership in the
United States is the hallmark of the middle class and represents much of its
wealth.
Note, however, that the plutocrats fought back and have
been gradually disassembling the tax structure and policies that allowed the
middle class to grow. Return on capital
is returning to previous levels and the rate of growth is falling. Piketty provides this explanation for the
dynamic involved:
“….it is important to note that
the effect of the tax on capital income is not to reduce the total accumulation
of wealth but to modify the structure of the wealth distribution over the long
run. In terms of the theoretical model,
as well as in the historical data, an increase in the tax on capital income
from 0 to 30 percent (reducing the net return on capital from 5 to 3.5 percent)
may well leave the total stock of capital unchanged over the long run for the
simple reason that the decrease in the upper centile’s share of wealth is
compensated by the rise of the middle class.
This is precisely what happened in the twentieth century—although the
lesson is sometimes forgotten today.”
If the increase in taxation of capital income helped create
the middle class, the decrease in such taxation could lead to the diminishment
of the middle class—an effect that seems obvious today.
Piketty looked closely at data on inheritance flows of
wealth in France to see if there was evidence that the extreme concentration of
wealth that existed in Europe prior to World War I might be returning. France is the country with the best
recordkeeping of wealth transfers. The
results are discussed in Inheritance, thePropagation of Wealth, and Inequality.
In summary, Piketty found that that inheritance flows fell to a minimum
and bottomed out around 1970. Since that
point they have been steadily climbing. Extrapolations
based on reasonable growth and return on investment scenarios indicate that
inherited wealth will grow to near the levels of the prewar years in
France.
There is an importance difference between that earlier
era and the current one. The creation of
a significant middle class has led to a de-concentration of wealth in the sense
that instead of a few extremely wealthy families, there is a broader base of merely
wealthy families. However, this wealth
is distributed in such a way that a significant fraction of the population is
capable of propagating to their children assets that will allow them to
continue to reside in this wealthy class.
Piketty suggests that of the people born in France in the 1970-1980 timeframe
about 12% will receive an inheritance in the form of gifts and bequests
equivalent to $1 million or more. He
expects that number to increase to 15% for those born in the 2010-2020 period.
The fear is that as the importance of inherited wealth
grows it will produce a bifurcated society in which the majority gains little
or nothing by inheritance, and 10-15% gains a sufficient amount to guarantee that
they remain in the class of the wealthy.
This is a situation more reminiscent of an aristocracy than a meritocracy. Piketty provides us this warning:
“This is….a fairly disturbing
form of inequality, which is in the process of attaining historically
unprecedented heights. It is also more
difficult to represent artistically or to correct politically, because it is a
commonplace inequality opposing broad segments of the population rather than
pitting a small elite against the rest of society.”
Piketty has provided us with a clear message: taxing
wealth and wealth’s income can lead to a more fair distribution of wealth as
well as healthy economic growth. If you
do not like the direction in which society is moving, you will have to
intervene and change things—as you once did in the past.
Capitalism is the offspring of society; society is not
the offspring of capitalism.
Excellent summary of the most significant aspect of Thomas Piety's book. I stumbled across your blog while debating Piety and the economy with some libertarians. I really like your closing thought. Well done.
ReplyDelete