Arlie Russell Hochschild is a sociologist at the
University of California at Berkeley who was determined to understand why
people in deep red states voted the way they did and what it was that drove the
reasoning they used in deciding how to vote.
She chose to study a region in Louisiana that is home to the oil and
petrochemical industries because she was particularly interested in determining
why a people who lived in an area made toxic by industry would be dead set
against environmental regulation.
Hochschild visited with many Louisianans over a period of
about five years trying to gain understanding. She
presented her findings in the book Strangers in Their Own Land: Anger and Mourning on the American Right. What she learned about their Tea Party leanings has been discussed in Strangers in Their Own Land: Republican Voters in the South. The attitudes
toward industry, religion, and the environment have been discussed in Louisiana Turns Itself into an Industrial Sacrifice Zone. Hochschild proposed
that what she observed in Louisiana in terms of economic development was a
consistent red state strategy—the low road—which could be compared with a blue
state strategy—the high road. This
latter subject will be the topic here.
Many of the people Hochschild met had been residing in
essentially the same area for generations.
The association with place—and environment—was very strong. It was very important for them to continue to
inhabit the area in which they had grown up.
For that to happen, it was essential that jobs be created. In fact, they were willing, begrudgingly, to
allow their environment to be plundered in order to obtain jobs.
This is the reasoning Hochschild saw in play in Louisiana.
“The logic was this. The more oil, the more jobs. The more jobs, the more prosperity, and the
less need for government aid. And the
less the people depend on government—local, state, or federal—the better off
they will be. So to attract more oil
jobs, the state has to offer financial ‘incentives’ to oil companies to get
them to come. That incentive money will
have to be drawn from the state budget, which may lead to the firing of public
sector workers, which, painful as it might seem, reduces reliance on government
and lowers taxes. It is a red state
tactic. But the paradox is that it goes
with being a poor state with a lot of problems.”
Hochschild discusses this paradox with Paul Templet “a
PhD in chemical physics” who taught at Louisiana State University and for four
years was head of the Louisiana Department of Environmental Quality. Templet was asked if the welcoming of oil
companies had reduced poverty.
“’No,’ he answers, Louisiana was
poor before oil came, and we’re poor today—the second poorest in the U.S.’ In 1979, 19 percent of Louisianans lived
below the poverty line; in 2014 it was 18 percent. In addition, ill-schooled poor people of any
race find it hard to get the kind of highly skilled permanent jobs oil brings
in. And oil hadn’t improved the
schools—they are financed by local property taxes, which are higher in rich
areas and lower in poor ones.”
But if the oil industry brings in high paying jobs,
shouldn’t that lead to economic growth and higher income for residents?
“One defense of oil jobs was
that they were highly paid and that salaries would ‘trickle down’ through
consumption that increased jobs and wages of other workers. But did it?
‘Not much,’ Templet says. That’s
because oil wages don’t trickle down; they leak out.”
A number of factors lead to this leakage. Most of the oil and petrochemical industries
are either foreign owned or located elsewhere in the US. Profits are then generally distributed
elsewhere, with dividend recipients most likely enjoying the social amenities—such
as good public schools and a healthy environment— provided by more advanced
countries or those available in the blue states. Just because an executive builds a chemical
plant in a poor region of Louisiana, that does not mean she wishes to live
there herself, or force many others to live there either. Those who could bring real wealth into the state
stay away.
When a plant moves to Louisiana it generates a large
number of jobs—temporarily. Skilled
craftsmen are required for the building of the plant, but because Louisiana
does not provide those skilled workers, most of them are imported from outside
the state, or outside the country. Less-skilled
workers are also needed, but companies prefer to use even lower paid workers
than they can legally employ in the US if they can get away with it. Most of the earnings of both classes of
workers leave the state.
“The industry is highly
automated. To build a petrochemical plant, you need many construction workers for
a temporary period, and then their job is over.
To run a petrochemical plant,
you need a small number of highly trained engineers, chemists, and operators to
keep watch over panels of gauges and to know what to do when there’s trouble. Then you need a few repairmen…”
“But a fracking boom was on, and
maybe that meant more jobs coming in.
According to the 2014….Southwest Louisiana Regional Impact Study, some
18,000 jobs, a small portion of them permanent, would open up by 2018. But seven out of ten of these jobs would be
filled, the report said, by workers from outside southwest Louisiana. Many companies would recruit professionals
from around the world. Construction
workers building the ‘man camps’—barracks within enclosed encampments—were
Mexican, people said. The man camps
would house 5,000 pipefitters, an undisclosed number of them Filipinos on
temporary visas. Filipino workers have
worked for over a decade on oil platforms in the Gulf.”
What Hochschild saw in Louisiana is an example of what is
referred to as a low-road strategy, one that is common in red states. It involves eliminating union representation
of workers as much as possible, keeping wages and taxes low, and removing any
regulations and procedures that might be inhibit businesses from doing exactly
what they would like to do. This
strategy has worked well over the years throughout the South as a means of
luring industries away from other parts of the country. But for it to continue to work, wages must be
kept lower than other regions in a kind of race to the bottom. And in feeding incentives to industries, the
states necessarily cut back on social benefits for its citizens. The state is in effect weakening itself and
becoming more submissive to the will of the corporations.
Hochschild’s source, Templet, provides this perspective
on Louisiana..
“As companies squeeze favors out
of the state, he argued, the more urgent its citizens’ needs for good schools
and hospitals, the less the poor are able to use what opportunities exist, and
the more atrophied become other sectors of the economy—which further concentrates
power in the hands of oil.”
If this is the low-road, red-state strategy, what might
be the high-road, blue-state strategy?
“The ‘high road’ strategy….is to
stimulate new jobs by creating an attractive public sector, as California did
in Silicon Valley and Washington State did in Seattle.”
This implies a strategy that keeps wages high enough that
people can live without public income support, investing in good public
schools, healthcare, a healthy environment, and effective infrastructure. These things of course are all expensive and
require significant revenue from taxes.
They also come with a host of regulatory constraints on businesses.
It is difficult to conjure up two more diametrically
opposed views of the path to economic development. How well do they work? Hochschild provides us with some data.
Let’s begin with some big picture considerations.
“Across the country, red states
are poorer and have more teen mothers, more divorce, worse health, more
obesity, more trauma-related deaths, more low-birth-weight babies, and lower
school enrollment. On average, people in
red states die five years earlier than people in blue states. Indeed, the gap in life expectancy between
Louisiana (75.7) and Connecticut (80.8) is the same as that between the United
States and Nicaragua. Red states suffer
more in another highly important but little-known way, one that speaks to the
very biological self-interest in health and life: industrial pollution.”
The willingness to tolerate pollution in the name of
economic development was not a Louisiana attribute; it was a true red state marker.
“….a startling 2012 study by
sociologist Arthur O’Connor that showed that residents of red states suffer
higher rates of industrial pollution than do residents of blue states. Voters in the twenty-two states that voted
Republican in the five presidential elections between 1992 and 2008—and
generally call for less government
regulation of business—lived in more
polluted environments. Residents in the
twenty-two Democratic states that generally favor stricter regulation, he
found, live in cleaner environments.”
This is what one might expect from attitudes about
government regulation. But how has this
affected economic development.
“A 1993 study that compared
states’ ratings on strictness of environmental protection with indicators of
economic health (overall growth, employment growth, construction growth) over
twenty years found that stronger environmental standards have not limited the
relative pace of economic growth.”
“In a 2001 study of new air-quality
regulations for manufacturing plants in the Los Angeles area, researchers
reported no evidence that local air-quality regulation, among the strictest in
the nation, substantially reduced employment.”
“A 2002 study also analyzed the
impact of environmental regulations on four industries that generate
significant pollution—and might therefore be expected to suffer losses from the
effects of environmental regulation. In
two of the four industries researchers studied (plastics and petroleum), the
net employment impact of the environmental regulations was small but positive,
while in the other two industries (pulp and paper, and iron and steel) there
was no statistically significant impact.”
“….a 2008 study found that
investments in environmental protection create some jobs and displace others,
but that the net effect on employment is positive. In fact, environmental protection is itself a
major sales-generating, job-creating industry.”
Environmental protection depends on the development of
new technologies. The states that invest
in education and encourage technology development will be the places that
benefit from environmental regulation, while the states that promote low wages
at the expense of educational development will lose. It seems the red states acquiesce to a
program of accepting the pollution needed to produce the objects blue states desire
and then paying the blue states to provide them the technology with which to
mitigate that pollution.
Environmental pollution is not the only issue related to
strategies for encouraging economic development. It seems the red-state strategy of providing
incentives to industry has generally been counterproductive.
“A 2010 study, based on analysis
of national surveys of 700 to 1,000 local governments from 1994, 1999, and 2004
that tracked the use of business incentives over time, found that governments
that rely most heavily on incentives may face more intergovernmental
competition, stagnating or declining economies, and lower tax bases. For such governments, business incentives may
contribute to a cycle of destructive competition.”
The decision to provide incentives to industry means that
funds will have to be withdrawn from some other areas. This sets up competition between education and
other social services for diminishing resources. Couple this with a willingness to allow
industry to set low wage scales and you have created a situation where workers will
have an increased need for those diminished services—a kind of race to the
bottom.
Several studies have demonstrated that the blue-state
strategy of demanding “living” wages and providing the educational
opportunities to make workers skillful enough to justify those wages is the
appropriate path to follow. Consider
this study of the construction industry: The Economic, Fiscal, and Social Impacts of State Prevailing Wage Laws: Choosing Between the High Road and the Low Road in the Construction Industry. It provided these conclusions.
“Prevailing wage legislation is
part of a broader set of interrelated institutional arrangements that promote a
strong construction industry and a thriving middle class, including a stronger
emphasis on apprenticeship training, skilled workmanship, workplace safety,
increased access to health insurance and retirement security. Prevailing wage laws support a high road
economy by establishing the underlying legal framework for a construction
industry that provides the skills needed to build quality infrastructure for a
growing, technologically-sophisticated, and competitive economy. By fostering
an economy with a strong middle class, prevailing wages promote sound public
sector budgets at all levels of government.”
“Legislators have a choice
between this construction industry high road and the low road that leads to
less training, lower quality workmanship, more waste and inefficiency at the
worksite, higher levels of poverty, increased taxpayer burdens, and reduced
economic activity.”
A study by the International Economic Development Council,
Creating Quality Jobs: Transforming the Economic Development Landscape, examines case studies of places that
attempted to improve local economic development. The locations were as varied as Tupelo,
Mississippi and San Jose, California.
The conclusion was that the high road is the path to pursue. A skilled work force is the basis for job
development and economic growth.
“The conclusion that emerges from an assessment of
these cases is simple (with complex solutions)—a more volatile and dynamic
economy is driven increasingly by the skills of people. The cases indicate that
indeed aligning skills and jobs is now sine qua non for economic development.
This is the heart of the transforming landscape of economic development.”
Hochschild is drawn to the conclusion that the red and
blue states, taken together, form a cooperative industrial ecology—but one that
benefits the blue states more.
“As sociologist Richard Florida
notes, ‘Blue state knowledge economies run on red state energy. Red state energy economies, in their turn,
depend on dense coastal cities and metro areas, not just as markets and sources
of migrants, but for the technology and talent they supply.”
“Indeed, Louisianans are
sacrificial lambs to the entire American industrial system. Left or right, we all happily use plastic
combs, toothbrushes, cell phones and cars, but we don’t all pay for it with
high pollution. As research for this
book shows, red states pay for it more—partly through their own votes for
easier regulation and partly through their exposure to a social terrain of
politics, industry, television channels, and a pulpit that invites them to do
so. In one way, people in blue states
have their cake and eat it too, while many in red states have neither.”
No comments:
Post a Comment